Showing posts with label financial crisis. Show all posts
Showing posts with label financial crisis. Show all posts

Sunday, December 19, 2010

The Moral Case for the Free Market in the Light of the Financial Crisis (Part II)

In a previous article I outlined the moral basis for the premise that free market economics are the optimal option for economic development. I also argued that -in the light of the financial crisis-the rationale behind these arguments has been significantly challenged. Indeed, the solution to the crisis-that of collectivising risk-not only confirms moral hazard but actively encourages it in future.

 Capitalism doesn't work unless the capitalists and the capital issuers (the banks) are both working under competitive conditions benefitting from Adam Smith's invisible hand but always managing the risk of his slap. Unfortunately one side of the capitalist equation (the banks) has not been working under this premise in recent years.

It's time to look at the scorecard in terms of the arguments outlined earlier and, see how they have fared.


The Argument from Materialism

The strongest moral defence for bailing out the banks was that it would eventually make the environment better for everyone. I think the logic is indisputable, in that as total collapse of the banking system would shave benefitted no one. However, this argument comes with significant caveats. The principle is that all would benefit and that there would not be a significant transfer of wealth and resources from one group to another via collectivisation and redistribution. Unfortunately, this has not happened.

The reality is that significant risk has been transferred to the public from the banking system. Central \banks took on toxic assets. Sovereign Debt Fears have exposed peripheral Europe to significant drags on growth that affect everyone. Furthermore, the actions of the Central Banks have, thus far, ensured that whilst the banking sector has been recapitalised and their staff are enjoying the benefits, they feel the need to hoard cash. In a sense, the banks are doing exactly what they did before the crisis. In other words, taking the benefits and rewards whilst passing on the risk to the taxpayer. They are parlaying the system in a zero sum game that is directly hurting the populace at large.

For example, the UK banks according to the CEBR, they paid their staff £7bn in bonus. Saviles (the upmarket real estate agent) estimate that £1.6bn of this will go into the London housing market. Meanwhile, the UK has loaned the Irish £7bn in order to help out their Sovereign Debt crisis, ostensibly so that it doesn't hit the UK banks.

These actions (by the banks) are the height of irresponsibility. They know full well that the Sovereign Debt on their balance sheets (remember that the risk to public debt increased by taking on banks toxic assets) threatens their capital/asset ratio, so why are they awarding themselves bonuses?

 So, in conclusion, the UK taxpayer has increased risk, higher taxes and now higher house prices to pay thanks to a redistribution of return and risk.


The Epistemic Argument for the Market
Libertarian defenders of this argument will argue that the banks should have been allowed to fail and, that this is part of the process. However, the problem with this argument is that it doesn’t devolve the free market system from the responsibility of creating the financial crisis in the first place. Moreover, allowing the banks to go bust was simply not an option.
The banks and their employees were incentivised, under guiding principles of self interest, in order to maximise profits. Unfortunately, this profit maximisation came at the expense of the taxpayer, the shareholder and the economy at large. The people garnering excessive rewards were not exposing themselves to the risk. In fact, the greater risk was in not complying, because if the employees didn’t take part in the game, then they could have lost their jobs.
The essence of the problem is that the banks were leveraged and all following the same directional strategy. The forces of competition rely upon accountability and also on the fear of failure. It relies upon large companies acting under the same conditions of competition as the smallest entrepreneur is subject to. None of these conditions applied.
Indeed, if we go back to the arguments postulated by the Austrian School over the difficulties of simulating market pricing, we get to a curious irony. Many of the banks were arguing that they didn’t need to engage in mark-to-market pricing of their CDO’s because the market was artificially pricing them lowly and, forced selling would only exacerbate the problem. Similarly, they spent large parts of 2008, trying to justify loss provisions based on their own assumptions of the housing market. In a sense, they repeated the inevitable errors of centralised pricing.
They did so, despite being guided by market competition.


The Argument From Autonomy
As discussed previously, much of this argument is rendered complicated by definitive arguments over positive and negative liberty. Assuming that ‘autonomy’ means needs can be satiated; we see that the question posed here can be defined as, autonomous to do what?
If we accept that we can define satiable needs, and start out to do so, I think that it could be argued that employment, housing and raising a family are all essential aspects of the ‘good life’. It is hard to argue that this autonomy has increased over the last few years. Not only have the redistributive aspects of Government policy (as outlined above) reduced the material prospects for all, but they have also entrenched the vested self interests that actively deny young people the opportunity to do this.
The Government has allowed the banks to game the system and made the conscious decision that, the solution to the problem was ‘more of the same’. They have artificially supported the banking system and the UK housing market. There remains an undersupply of housing in London and South East. 
It need not have happened like this. The opportunity was there to generate growth by relaxing planning restrictions in London. Such action would have produced GDP growth, employment, and made housing more affordable in the areas where people actually want to live. Instead a decision was made to shore up the wealth of a select few in the UK by continuing to artificially rig the London housing market.
It should not be lost on the reader that the beneficiaries of these actions are-in many cases-the self same people that benefitted from the creation of the financial crisis. In 2008, a Savile’s strategist informed me that around 25% of overseas high end (houses £4m and above) where overseas bankers working in the UK.
None of these actions has increased the autonomous options available to most.

The Argument From an Increasing Intellectual Quotient
The desire of the banking industry to ‘intellectualise’ their activities in respect of replacing good ol’ fashioned lending from customer deposits, towards reliance on short term wholesale funding was a serious defect of the system. Similarly, the creation of ‘off-balance’ sheet accounting which enabled the banks to take on significant directional leverage helped create the ensuing crisis.
This ‘intellectualisation’ was anything but intellectually enhancing. In fact, it was a shabby and reckless attempt to maximise short term profits which ultimately ended up in a collectivisation of the losses due to it.
The aftermath of the crisis has brought about an increasing focus by regulators to discourage this kind of financial engineering with derivatives trading. Whether, they will be successful or not is another question.

Creation, Globalisation and the Poor
The last three arguments are best dealt with in one section. Firstly, it is undoubtedly true that free markets engender greater creativity. However, as we have seen, this creativity can sometimes be channelled towards destructive or exploitative purposes which curtail others creativity. The banks gamed the system to the taxpayers’ expense. This is not an act of ‘creativity’ worthy of the name.
Globalisation as actually made the situation worse. It has encouraged greater correlation of markets and therefore amplified the risks when things go wrong. I wonder out loud whether the Asian Financial Crisis (97-98) will be the last major regional crisis not to significantly affect the global economy in a synchronised and coordinated manner.
As for the poor, I fail to see how the redistribution of resources and wealthy that has, knowingly, taken place as a result of bailing out the banks, has in any way contributed to social mobility or advantage to the poor. On the contrary, unemployment is still very high in the States (the US is not a country structured with a welfare system to deal with these problems) and remains persistently high in Europe.

Conclusions
The narrative of this article has been consistently negative. I make no apologies for that. The behaviour of the banks is morally unacceptable. Moreover, regulators are at fault for not upholding the same standards of free market accountability on the banks as they would for anyone else. Whilst the libertarian approach is exposed as a fallacy, it does not mean that the morals and principles of the free market are not the optimal approach. However, they only acquire moral validity by their actions and their results.
The solution to the problems engendered by allowing banks to operate under ‘free markets’, seems to inevitably end up in collectivising and redistributing resources towards them. Therefore, it is better to take collective action before hand, in order to make them directly accountable for their actions. The libertarian approach fails and the moral arguments in favour of it are bankrupt. ‘Too Big To Fail’ is not an option anymore.

Saturday, November 20, 2010

Mervyn King on the Financial Crisis

On Monday 25th of October the Governor of the Bank of England gave a forthright speech on the banking industry. He pulled no punches and it makes fascinating reading, from a man at the epicentre of the present financial crisis.

Why did the Crisis Occur?

King notes that despite the severe equity market falls in 1987 and 2000-2003 we did not see a comparable effect to the economy as we have with the banking crisis. He goes on to enquire

Unfortunately, such crises are occurring more frequently and on an ever
larger scale. Why?

I think we have to note that not only are they increasing, but they are becoming more globally correlated. Furthermore, the primary solution-lower interest rates-seems to be needing lower and lower rates to deal with the problem.

One of the reasons given by King for the increases in crises is the explosion of banks –in particular big banks-balance sheets, primarily as a result of an increase in leverage.

in the US, the top ten banks amount to over 60% of GDP, six times larger than the top ten fifty years ago. Bank of America today accounts for the same proportion of the US banking system as all of the top 10 banks put together in 1960.

Furthermore, banks have resulted to using more short term wholesale funding. At this point it is worth noting that it was this increasing reliance on short term funding that characterised HBOS in the credit crunch. HBOS moved away from relying on customer deposits (the traditional building society model) in favour of using short term wholesale market funding. This is relevant because HBOS difficulties were emanating from its commercial banking rather than from investment banking. In other words, the distinction between commercial and investment banking is not entirely clear here. This creates difficulties for those (such as Paul Volcker) who want these activities to be separated in order to avoid the danger of ‘too big to fail’ investment banks blowing up.

Indeed, King questions how this separation would work in practice, but I suspect that the development of these 'shadow' banking arrangements would not have occurred, had there been separation.


 
How Markets are Becoming Increasingly Correlated

King points out that this encourages greater interconnectedness in the system, and this caused knock on effects to sentiment.

Damningly, he goes on to point out

Moreover, a financial sector that takes on risk with the implicit support of the tax-payer can generate measured value added that reflects not genuine risk-bearing but the upside profits from the implicit subsidy.

 
and

But part of the value added of the financial sector prior to the crisis reflected temporary profits from taking risk and it was only after September 2008 that much of that so-called economic activity resulted in enormous reported losses by banks.

 
 Too Big to Fail

King goes on

Institutions supplying such services are quite simply too important to fail. Everyone knows it. So, highly risky banking institutions enjoy implicit public sector support. In turn, implied public support the banks an incentive to take on yet more risk, knowing that, if things go well, they will reap the rewards while the public sector will foot the bill if things go wrong. Greater risk begets greater size, most probably greater importance to the functioning of the economy, higher implicit public subsidies, and hence yet larger incentives to take risk

 
The rest of the speech goes on to discuss the various mechanisms by which solutions can be found. These include things like formally separating banking activities; increasing capital-asset ratio requirements; taxing the ‘polluter’ and, limited purpose banking so that the maturity mismatch is reduced or even eradicated. 

It is a fascinating speech.and I would encourage all, to read it in full.

Some Thoughts

I would like to focus on the incentive effect and also on how many aspects of the crises can be seen to be endemic in society.  It would be wrong to think of the crisis as being hermetically sealed to the banking industry. The tone of the speech seems to be echoing Taleb’s maxim that the bankers took all the rewards for risk but passed on all the costs to the taxpayer. It’s worse than that though. It appears that HBOS , Lloyds TSb et al were being incentivised to become ‘too big to fail’ so that they could ensure they would get bailed out.

Worryingly, the increase in ‘value added’ by the banks before 2008 was a chimera, according to King.  However, the illusion did not extend to scale of the salaries that the banking sector paid itself.  Those massive increases were real. Very real. Furthermore, they largely contributed to the increase in the high end if the London property market, or at least, that is what a strategist from Saviles told me at an AGM when we discussed it. Of course, as the high end goes up, so the rest follows. The sub-prime punters merely wanted a piece of the action too.

Therefore, the asset class –property- at the epicentre of the losses on the balance sheets of the banks in the UK, was actually being pushed higher by the people reaping the rewards of putting the economy in jeopardy. They were incentivised to do so by ‘gaming’ the system, in order to ensure that the taxpayers would bail them out.

The idea that the losses on sub prime in the States or UK could be mitigated towards that segment (relatively small) of the banking industry, unfortunately, proved fallacious for many of the reasons that King outlines.


Globalisation Increasing Correlation?
Similarly, this interconnectedness ensured that the financial system was in fact set up in one direction and, in my opinion, it is this increase in directionality-rather than the leverage per se- that caused the problem. For example, a lot of spilt ink was used in 2008 arguing over whether institutions should have to ‘mark-to-market’ some of the illiquid assets (CDOs etc) on their balance sheets. Banking apologists are keen to blame regulators for forcing them to ‘weaken’ their balance sheets unnecessarily in this way.  However, if all the financial institutions hadn’t been in the same direction then some of them would have been in shape to buy these ‘undervalued’ assets. Something only has a value for what somebody else is willing to pay for it.

The problem lies in the increase in the increasing correlation and directionality of markets. This is made worse by the fact that, if everyone is positioned in the same direction, the winner will be the one that takes on the most risk. A scenario which results in money and power being allocated towards the people who have the least understanding of risk. With increasing globalisation, these aspects are likely to increase until action is taken to strike at the nexus.

Source: